Skip to main content
Log in

Distress risk puzzle and analyst forecast optimism

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A general consensus in the literature is that financial analysts make optimistic forecasts. That is, they tend to underreact to negative but overreact to positive information. In this study, we invoke this idea to provide an explanation for the distress risk puzzle, the phenomenon that high distress risk firms deliver anomalously low subsequent returns. We find that analysts underestimate the implication of the poor performance of higher distress risk firms, and thus make EPS and sales forecasts that are generally more optimistic than those for the lower distress risk firms. Because market respond to the analyst forecasts, investors initially overvalue the high distress risk firms; later on, when those firms report less than expected performance, analysts revise their forecasts downwards that in turn cause the high distress risk firms to earn low future returns composing of both immediate-forecast-revision responses and post-forecast-revision price drifts. We further document that (quarter) earnings announcements convey a substantial amount of information that roughly drives more than 60% of the analyst forecast revisions and 30% of the revision-related market responses.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Note only financial analysts, there is evidence indicating that other professional market participants are making over-optimistic assessments for poor firms. For example, Cao et al. (2017) find that auditors seem to significantly underreact to payout decreases (i.e., negative signals) but react appropriately to payout increases (i.e., positive signals) in their going-concern decisions for financially distressed clients.

  2. By using three independent distress risk measures for the analyses, our paper provides counterevidence for the query that the distress risk puzzle may be merely special case results due to the use of some distress risk measures such as the O-SCORE (e.g. Kim 2013).

  3. As robustness check, we follow an anonymous reviewer’s suggestion to construct another default risk measure by the method in Campbell et al. (2008). We repeat the main analysis by the new risk measure and results are qualitatively the same. To save space, we do not include the results in the paper but are available upon request.

  4. Another criticism of using O-SCORE as distress risk measure is that O-SCORE is highly correlated with the firm’s accruals (Kim 2013). In other words, the distress risk puzzle may be just a manifesto of the accrual anomaly (Sloan 1996) that motives our study to using also probability of default and credit rating as extra measures of distress risk to provide evidence that the distress risk puzzle is not simply equivalent to the accrual anomaly.

  5. We also measure the size-adjusted CRET that show similar decreasing trends along the three sets of DR groups: from − 10.91 to − 26.57% for osgrp, from − 11.24 to − 15.65% for pdgrp, and from − 7.96 to − 24.81% for ratgrp.

  6. We do not consider the forecast errors and revisions announced in the 11th month and 12th fiscal month because the number of observations in these 2 months normally decrease to less than 10% the observations of other fiscal months.

  7. We assume analysts are basing on known (financial) information of the firm to make their forecasts, so we use the financial variables of the firms as of their last fiscal year-ends to construct their distress risk measures and other control variables.

  8. A puzzling observation is that firm size has effectively no explanatory power to sales forecast errors, suggesting that size may have different implications to the EPS and sales forecast errors. We leave this question to future research.

  9. We thank and follow an anonymous reviewer’s suggestion to include return skewness as a control for investors’ preference for returns (Conrad et al. 2014).

  10. Teoh and Wong (2002) study the effect of analyst optimism on the performance of equity issuers. They find evidence that analysts are over optimistic in subsequent years for issuers reporting higher accruals, thus causing the underperformance of the issuers after the issue years. They fit analyst forecast errors by excess and expected accruals, and then regress the subsequent returns of issuers on the fitted errors and residuals. Our paper uses fitted forecast revisions as the explanatory variable so that we can observe directly how revisions of the biased forecasts drive the returns.

  11. By including both EPS and sales forecast revisions as the control variables, we can see whether sales forecast revisions contribute to the price drifts as well. To the best of our knowledge, the post-sales-forecast-revision price drifts are not studied in prior literature.

  12. See the papers mentioned in the Introduction.

References

  • Abarbanell JS (1991) Do analysts’ earnings forecasts incorporate information in prior stock price changes? J Acc Econ 14(2):147–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abarbanell JS, Bernard VL (1992) Tests of analysts’ overreaction/underreaction to earnings information as an explanation for anomalous stock price behavior. J Finance 47(3):1181–1207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anginer D, Yıldızhan C (2018) Is there a distress risk anomaly? Pricing of systematic default risk in the cross-section of equity returns. Rev Finance 22(2):633–660

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Avramov D, Chordia T, Jostova G, Philipov A (2013) Anomalies and financial distress. J Financ Econ 108(1):139–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barron OE, Kim O, Lim SC, Stevens DE (1998) Using analysts’ forecasts to measure properties of analysts’ information environment. Acc Rev 73(4):421–433

    Google Scholar 

  • Bharath ST, Shumway T (2008) Forecasting default with the Merton distance to default model. Rev Financ Stud 21(3):1339–1369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black F, Scholes M (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J Polit Econ 81(3):637–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradshaw MT, Richardson SA, Sloan RG (2001) Do analysts and auditors use information in accruals? J Acc Res 39(1):45–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradshaw MT, Richardson SA, Sloan RG (2006) The relation between corporate financing activities, analysts’ forecasts and stock returns. J Acc Econ 42(1–2):53–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell JY, Hilscher J, Szilagyi JAN (2008) In search of distress risk. J Finance 63(6):2899–2939

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao J, Kubick TR, Masli AN (2017) Do corporate payouts signal going-concern risk for auditors? Evidence from audit reports for companies in financial distress. Rev Quant Financ Acc 49(3):599–631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chahine S (2004) Long-run abnormal return after IPOs and optimistic analysts’ forecasts. Int Rev Financ Anal 13(1):83–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng CS, Agnes KC Kenneth, Ohlson JA (2020) Analyst forecasts: sales and profit margins. Rev Acc Stud 25:54–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chu J, Ki ES (2019) Do auditor’s efforts of interim review curb the analyst forecast’s walkdown. J Asian Finance Econ Bus 6(2):45–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clement MB, Tse SY (2003) Do investors respond to analysts’ forecast revisions as if forecast accuracy is all that matters? Acc Rev 78(1):227–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad J, Kapadia N, Xing Y (2014) Death and jackpot: why do individual investors hold overpriced stocks? J Financ Econ 113(3):455–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowen A, Groysberg B, Healy P (2006) Which types of analyst firms are more optimistic? J Acc Econ 41(1–2):119–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crosbie P, Bohn J (2003) Modeling default risk. In: World scientific reference on contingent claims analysis in corporate finance, pp 471–506

  • Da Z, Gao PJ (2010) Clientele change, liquidity shock, and the return on financially distressed stocks. J Financ Quant Anal 45(1):27–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das S, Levine CB, Sivaramakrishnan K (1998) Earnings predictability and bias in analysts’ earnings forecasts. Acc Rev 73(2):277–294

    Google Scholar 

  • Debondt WFM, Thaler RH (1990) Do security analysts overreact? Am Econ Rev 80(2):52–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Dechow PM, Hutton AP, Sloan RG (2000) The relation between analysts’ forecasts of long-term earnings growth and stock price performance following equity offerings. Contemp Acc Res 17(1):1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dichev ID (1998) Is the risk of bankruptcy a systematic risk? J Finance 53(3):1131–1147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drake M, Myers L (2011) Analysts’ accrual-related over-optimism: do analyst characteristics play a role? Rev Acc Stud 16(1):59–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dugar A, Nathan S (1995) The effect of investment banking relationships on financial analysts’ earnings forecasts and investment recommendations. Contemp Acc Res 12(1):131–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterwood JC, Nutt SR (1999) Inefficiency in analysts’ earnings forecasts: systematic misreaction or systematic optimism? J Finance 54(5):1777–1797

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elgers PT, Lo MH, Pfeiffer RJ Jr. (2001) Delayed security price adjustments to financial analysts’ forecasts of annual earnings. Acc Rev 76(4):613–632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elton EJ, Gruber MJ, Gultekin M (1981) Expectations and share prices. Manag Sci 27(9):975–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French K (1992) The cross-section of expected stock returns. J Finance 47(2):427–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis J, Philbrick D (1993) Analysts’ decisions as products of a multi-task environment. J Acc Res 31(2):216–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fried D, Givoly D (1982) Financial analysts’ forecasts of earnings: a better surrogate for market expectations. J Account Econ 4(2):85–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garlappi L, Yan H (2011) Financial distress and the cross-section of equity returns. J Finance 66(3):789–822

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garlappi L, Shu T, Yan H (2008) Default risk, shareholder advantage, and stock returns. Rev Financ Stud 21(6):2743–2778

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • George TJ, Hwang CY (2010) A resolution of the distress risk and leverage puzzles in the cross section of stock returns. J Financ Econ 96(1):56–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Givoly D, Lakonishok J (1980) Financial analysts’ forecasts of earnings: their value to investors. J Bank Finance 4(3):221–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleason CA, Lee CMC (2003) Analyst forecast revisions and market price discovery. Acc Rev 78(1):193–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffin JM, Lemmon ML (2002) Book-to-market equity, distress risk, and stock returns. J Finance 57(5):2317–2336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gu Z, Xue J (2007) Do analysts overreact to extreme good news in earnings? Rev Quant Financ Acc 29(4):415–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayes RM (1998) The impact of trading commission incentives on analysts’ stock coverage decisions and earnings forecasts. J Acc Res 36(2):299–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes J, Liu J, Su W (2008) On the relation between predictable market returns and predictable analyst forecast errors. Rev Acc Stud 13(2/3):266–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hui KW, Yeung PE (2013) Underreaction to industry-wide earnings and the post-forecast revision drift. J Acc Res 51(4):701–737

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hwang L-S, Jan C-L, Basu S (1996) Loss firms and analysts’ earnings forecast errors. J Financ Statement Anal 1(2):13

    Google Scholar 

  • Imhoff EA Jr, Lobo GJ (1984) Information content of analysts’ composite forecast revisions. J Acc Res 22(2):541–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanagaretnam K, Lobo GJ, Mathieu R (2012) CEO stock options and analysts’ forecast accuracy and bias. Rev Quant Financ Acc 38(3):299–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim S (2013) What is behind the magic of O-Score? An alternative interpretation of Dichev’s (1998) bankruptcy risk anomaly. Rev Acc Stud 18(2):291–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang MH, Lundholm RJ (1996) Corporate disclosure policy and analyst behavior. Acc Rev 71(4):467–492

    Google Scholar 

  • Lim T (2001) Rationality and analysts’ forecast bias. J Finance 56(1):369–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin WC, Chang SC, Chen SS, Liao TL (2013) The over-optimism of financial analysts and the long-run performance of firms following private placements of equity. Finance Res Lett 10(2):82–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Livnat J, Zhang Y (2012) Information interpretation or information discovery: which role of analysts do investors value more? Rev Acc Stud 17(3):612–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McNichols M, O’Brien PC (1997) Self-selection and analyst coverage. J Acc Res 35:167–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1974) On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates. J Finance 29(2):449–470

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien PC (1988) Analysts’ forecasts as earnings expectations. J Acc Econ 10(1):53–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ohlson JA (1980) Financial ratios and the probabilistic prediction of bankruptcy. J Acc Res 18(1):109–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paleari S, Vismara S (2007) Over-optimism when pricing IPOs. Manag Finance 33(6):352–367

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan R, Servaes H (1997) Analyst following of initial public offerings. J Finance 52(2):507–529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sloan RG (1996) Do stock prices fully reflect information in accruals and cash flows about future earnings? Acc Rev 71(3):289–315

    Google Scholar 

  • So EC (2013) A new approach to predicting analyst forecast errors: do investors overweight analyst forecasts? J Financ Econ 108(3):615–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stickel SE (1991) Common stock returns surrounding earnings forecast revisions: more puzzling evidence. Acc Rev 66(2):402–416

    Google Scholar 

  • Teoh SH, Wong TJ (2002) Why new issues and high-accrual firms underperform: the role of analysts’ credulity. Rev Financ Stud 15(3):869–900

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vassalou M, Xing Y (2004) Default risk in equity returns. J Finance 59(2):831–868

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vazza D, Leung E, Alsati M, Katz M (2005) Creditwatch and rating outlooks: valuable predictors of ratings behavior. In: Standard and poor’s credit research paper

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper is supported by HKSAR Research Grants Council, Ealy Career Scheme, 2016/17 (PolyU 255056/16B). We appreciate the helpful comments and suggestions from Professor James Ohlson and participants at the 17th Annual International Conference on Accounting, the 10th International Conference of Japanese Accounting Review, and 2019 ATINER Conference. All errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to K. C. Kenneth Chu.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Table 7.

Table 7 Definitions of the major variables

Appendix 2: Distress risk measures

In this Appendix, we highlight the methods to calculate the three distress risk measures used in this paper. For further technical details, please refer to the reference papers being cited.

2.1 Appendix 2.1: O-SCORE

Similar to Dichev (1998), O-SCORE for firm j at the end of fiscal year t is calculated by Eq. (A1) below with the coefficients from the Model 1 in Ohlson (1980). For simplicity, firm and time subscripts are skipped.

$$\begin{aligned} {\text{O}} - {\text{SCORE}}_{{({\text{t}})}} & = - 1. 3 2- 0. 40 7*{ \log }\left( {{\text{total assets}}/{\text{GNP price}} - {\text{level index}}} \right) \, + { 6}.0 3*\left( {{\text{total liabilities}}/{\text{total assets}}} \right) \\ & \quad - 1. 4 3*\left( {{\text{working capital}}/{\text{total assets}}} \right) \, + \, 0.0 7 6*\left( {{\text{current liabilities}}/{\text{current assets}}} \right) - 1. 7 2*\left( { 1 {\text{ if total liabilities }} > {\text{ total assets}};{\text{ else }}0} \right) \\ & \quad - 2. 3 7*\left( {{\text{net income}}/{\text{total assets}}} \right) - 1. 8 3*\left( {{\text{funds from operations}}/{\text{total liabilities}}} \right) + \, 0. 2 8 5*\left( { 1 {\text{ if net loss for the last 2}} {\text{years}};{\text{ else }}0} \right) \\ & \quad - 0. 5 2 1*\left( {{\text{net income}}_{{({\text{t}})}} - {\text{net income}}_{{({\text{t}} - 1)}} \left] / \right[\left| {{\text{net income}}_{{({\text{t}})}} } \right| \, + \, \left| {{\text{net income}}_{{({\text{t}} - 1)}} } \right|} \right] \\ \end{aligned}$$
(A1)

2.2 Appendix 2.2: Probability of default

The probability of default (PD) for every firm each year is calculated in the spirit of the Merton (1974) model. When the market value of a firms’ total assets (hereafter, firm value) is greater than the face value of the firm’s debt outstanding, equity holders find it profitable to continue owning the firm. Otherwise, the equity holders declare bankruptcy. PD thus refers to the probability that the firm goes into bankruptcy within a certain period of time.

Firm value, V (> 0), is assumed following geometric Brownian motion:

$$dV = {{\upmu }}Vdt + \sigma_{v} VdW,$$

where µ is the expected return (continuously compounded) on V, \(\sigma_{v}\) is the volatility of V and dW is the standard Wiener process. The firm has an outstanding pure discount bond with face value F maturing in T years. Thus, the equity of the firm is a European call option on the underlying value of the firm with strike price and time-to-maturity equal F and T. By the Black–Scholes-Merton formula (Black and Scholes 1973), the value of the equity today, E, is given by

(B1)

where E is the market value of the firm’s equity, r is the instantaneous risk-free rate, Ɲ(·) is the cumulative standard normal distribution function, \({\text{d}}_{1} = \frac{{\ln \left( {\frac{V}{F}} \right) + \left( {r + 0.5\sigma_{v}^{2} } \right)T}}{{\sigma_{v} \sqrt T }}\) and \({\text{d}}_{2} = {\text{d}}_{1} - \sigma_{v} \sqrt T\). Furthermore, by the Ito’s lemma:

(B2)

where \(\sigma_{E}\) is the volatilities of the equity. Equation (B2) is to translate the volatility of equity to the volatility of total assets because the market value of total assets and its volatility are unobservable.

Following Bharath and Shumway (2008), Eqs. (B1) and (B2) are solved by an iterative procedure for V’s and \(\sigma_{v}\)’s every day in the previous year. (Specially, the initial value of \(\sigma_{v}\) is set to \(\sigma_{E}\)[E/(E + F)], where \(\sigma_{E}\), E and F are observable parameters. We then calculate the implied log return on assets each day and use the returns series to generate new estimates of \(\sigma_{v}\) and µ. The procedure is repeated until the calculated \(\sigma_{V}\) converges, i.e., the absolute difference in adjacent \(\sigma_{v}\)‘s is less than 10−3). Then the distance to default (DD) is calculated as \({\text{DD}} = \frac{{\ln \left( {\frac{V}{F}} \right) - \left( {{{\upmu }} - 0.5\sigma_{v}^{2} } \right)T}}{{\sigma_{v} \sqrt T }}\), and the corresponding (implied) probability of default within 1 year (assuming T = 1) is:

2.3 Appendix 2.3: Credit rating

The third proxy for distress risk is credit rating (RATING) that evaluate the credit risk of a firm as a debtor. The higher its credit rating, the higher the chance the firm will be able to pay back its outstanding debts (i.e., lower distress risk). Credit ratings of sample firms are obtained from Compustat, and following Avramov et al. (2013), we assign a numeric value to each symbolic ratings as AAA = 1, AA + = 2, etc. If the rating is below B–, the value is set to 17. The higher number of RATING, the higher the financial risk.

Appendix 3

See Table 8.

Table 8 Monthly EPS and sales forecast errors and forecast revisions

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chu, K.C.K., Zhai, W.H.S. Distress risk puzzle and analyst forecast optimism. Rev Quant Finan Acc 57, 429–460 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-020-00950-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-020-00950-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation